SHAPE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR IN MEDICINE
The key features of the
private sector in medical practice and health care are well known. Two
questions are relevant. What role should be assigned to it? How far and how
closely should it be regulated? Over the last several decades, independent
private medical practice has become widespread but has remained stubbornly urban with polyclinics, nursing
homes and hospitals proliferating often through doctor entrepreneurs. At our
level tertiary hospitals in major cities are in may cases run by business
houses and use corporate business strategies and hi-tech specialization to
create demand and attract those with effective demand or the critically
vulnerable at increasing costs. Standards in some of them are truly world class
and some who work there are outstanding leaders in their areas. But given the
commodification of medical care as part of a business plan it has not been
possible to regulate the quality, accountability and fairness in care through
criteria for accreditation, transparency in fees, medical audit, accountable
record keeping, credible grievance procedures etc. such accreditation, standard
setting and licensure systems are best done under self regulation, but self
regulation systems in India medical practice have been deficient in many
respects creating problem in credibility.
Acute care has become the
key priority and continues to attract manpower and investment into related
specialty education and facilities for technological improvement. Common
treatments, inexpensive diagnostic procedures and family medicine are replaced
and priced out of the reach of most citizens in urban areas.
Public health spending accounts for 25% of aggregate expenditure the balance being
out of pocket expenditure incurred by patients to private practitioners of
various hues. Public spending on health in India has itself declined after
liberalization from 1.3% of GDP in 1990 to 0.9%
in 1999. Central budget allocations for
health have stagnated at 1.3% to total
Central budget. In the States it has declined from 7.0% to 5.5.% of
State health budget. Consider the
contrast with the Bhore Committee recommendation of 15% committed to health from the revenue expenditure budget,
Indeed WHO had recommended 55 of GDP for
health. The current annual per capita public health expenditure is no more than
Rs.
160 and a recent World Bank review showed that over all primary health
services account for 58% of public
expenditure mostly but on salaries, and the secondary/tertiary sector for about 38%, perhaps the greater part going to
tertiary sector, including government funded medical education. Out of the
total primary care spending, as much as 85%
was spent on or curative services and only 15%
for preventive service. <World Bank 1995> about 47% of total Central and State budget is spent on curative care
and health facilities. This may seem excessive at first sight but in face the
figure is over 60% in comparable
countries, with the bulk of the expenditure devoted publicly funded care or on
mandated or voluntary risk pooling methods, in India close to 75% of all household expenditure on
health is spend from private funds and the consequent regressive effects on the
poor is not surprising. In this connection. Ehe proposals in the draft NHP 2000 are welcome seeking to restore the key
balance towards primary care, and bring it to internationally accepted
proportions in the course of this decade.
Private expenditure trends
Many surveys confirm that
when services are provided by private sector it is largely for ambulatory care
and less for inpatient carte. There are variations in levels of cost, pricing,
transactional conveniences and quality of services. There is evidence to suggest that disparities
in income as such do not make a difference in meeting health care costs, except
for catastrophic or life threatening situations Finally it has been established
that between 2/3rds to 3/4ths of all medical expenditure is spend on privately
provided care every household on the average spends up to 10% of annual household consumption in meeting
health care needs. This regressive burden shows up vividly in the cycle of
incomplete cure followed by recurrence of illness and drug resistance that the
poor face in diseases like TB or Kalazar or Malaria especially for daily wage
earners who cannot afford to be out of work.
Privatization has to be
distinguished from private medical practice which has always been substantial
within our mixed economy. What is critical however is the rapid commercialization
of private medical practice in particular uneven quality of care. There are
complex reasons for this trend. First is the high scarcity cost of good medical
education, and second the reward differential between public and corporate
tertiary hospitals leading to the reluctance of the young professional to be
lured away from the market to public service in rural areas and finally there
is the compulsion of returns on investment whenever expensive equipment in
installed as part of practice. Increasingly, this has shifted the balance from
individual practice to institutionalizes practice, in hospitals, polyclinics,-
Etc. this conjunction explodes into
unbearable cost escalation when backed by a third party payer system/- This in
turn induces increases in insurance premiums making such cover beyond the
capacity to pay. There is a distinct possibility
of such cycles of cost escalation periodically occurring in the
future, promoted further by global transfer of knowledge and software,
tele-medicine etc. especially after the advent of predictive medicine and gene
manipulation.
Doctors practicing in the private sector are
sometimes accused of prescribing excessive, expensive and nsky medicines and
with using rampant and less than justified use of technology for diagnosis and
treatment. Some method of accreditation of hospitals and facilities and better
licensure systems of doctors is likely within a decade. This will enables some
moderation in levels of charges in using new technology. High cost of care is
sometimes sought to be justified as necessary due to defensive medicine
practiced in order to meet risks under the Consumer Protection Act. There is little evidence from decisions of
Consumer Courts to justify such fears. While the line between mistaken
diagnosis and negligent behaviour will always remain thin, case law has already
begun to settle around the doctor's ability to
apply reasonable skills and not the highest degree of skill. What
has lieen established is the right of the
patient to question the treatment and procedures if there is failure to treat
according to standard medical practice or if less than adequate care was taken.
As health insurance gets established it may impost more stringent criteria and
restrictions on physician performance which may tempt them into defensive
medicine. There may also be attempt to collusive capture and (indirect
ownership) of insurance companies by corporate hospitals as in other countries.
Advances in medical technology are rapid and dominant and easily travel world wide
and often seen as good investment and brand equity in the private sector.
Private independent practices - and to
smaller extent hospitals, dispensaries, nursing homes tele- are seen as markets
for medical services with each segment seeking to maximize gains and build
mutually supporting links with other segments. More than one study on the
quality of care indicates that sometimes more services are performed to
maximize revenue, and services/ medicines are prescribed which ffl-e not always
necessary. Allegations are also widely made of collusive deals between doctors
and hospitals with commissions and cuts exchanged to promote needless referral,
drugs or procedures <World Bank A 1995>
Appropriate regulation is likely in the next decade for minimum standards and
accountability and that should consist of a balanced mix of self regulation
external regulation by standard setting and accreditation agencies including
private voluntary health insurance.
How far can health insurance help?
What constitutes a fair
distribution of the costs of care among different social groups will always be
a normative decision emerging out of political debate. It includes risk pooling initiatives for sharing costs among the healthy
and the sick leading to insurance schemes as a substitute for or as
supplementary to State provision for minimum uniform services. It also covers
risk sharing initiatives across wealth and income involving public policy
decisions on progressive taxation, merit subsidy and cross subsidization by dual
pricing. Both will continue to be necessary in our conditions with more
emphasis on risk sharing as growth picks up. Risk
pooling within private voluntary and mandated insurance schemes has
become inevitable in all countries because of the double burden of sickness and
to ensure that financial costs of treatment do not become an excessive burden
relative to incomes. It is difficult but necessary to embed these notions of
fair financing into legislation, regulations and schemes and programs equity is
aimed at in health care.
With the recent opening up
of the general Insurance sector to foreign companies, there is the prospect of
two trends. New insurance product will be putout so expand business more be
deepening than widening risk covered. The second trend would be to concentrate
on urban middle and upper classes and settled iobholders with capacity to pay
and with a perceived interest in good health of the family. Both trends make
sound business sense in a vast growth market and would increase extensive hospital
use and protection against huge hospitalization expenses, and promoted by urban
private hospitals since their clientele will increase.
Insurance is a welcome necessary step and must
doubtless expand to help in facilitating equitable health care to shift to
sections for which government is responsible. Indeed for those not able to
access insurance it is government that will have to continue to provide the
minimum services, and intervene against market failures including denial
through adverse selection or moral hazard. Indeed in the long run the degree of
inequity in health care after insurance systems are set up will depend
ironically on the strength and delivery of the public system as a counterpoise
in holding costs and relevance in technology.
The insurable population in
India has been assessed at 250 million
and at an average of Rs 1000/- per person
the premium amount per year would be Rs 25,000/- crores and is expected to
treble in ten years- While the insurance product will dutifully reflect the demands
of this colossal market and related technological developments in medicine, it
should be required to extend beyond hospitalization and cover domiciliary
treatment too in a big way; for instance, extending cover to ambulatory
maternal and selected chronic conditions like Asthma more prevalent among the
poor. The insurance regulatory authority has announced priority in licensing to
companies set up with health insurance as key business and has emphasized the
need for developing new products on fair terms to those at risk among the poor
and in rural areas. Much will turn on
what progress takes place through sound regulation covering aspects indicated
below. In order to be socially relevant and cominercially viable the scheme
must aim at a proper mix of health hazards and cover many broad social classes
and income groups. This is possible in poor locations or communities only if a
group view is taken and on chat basis a population-
based nsk is assessed and community rated premiums determined
covering families for all common illnesses and based on epidemiological
determined risk. In order that exclusions co-payments deductibles etc. remain
minimum and relevant to our social situation, some well judged government merit subsidy can be
incorporated into anti poverty family welfare or primary education or welfare
pension schemes meant for old age. Innovative community based new products can
be developed by using the scattered experience of such products for instance in
SEWA, so that a minimum core cover can be developed as a model for innovative
insurance by panchayats with reinsurance backup by companies and government
bearing part of promotional costs. The bulk of the formal sector maybe covered
by an expanded mandatory insurance with affordable cover and convenient modes
of premium payment. Outside the formal manufacturing sector innovate schemes
can be designed around specific occupation
groups in the informal sector which are steadily becoming a base for
old age pension entitlements, as in Kerala and Tamil Nadu - and brought under common risk rating.
Finally, as in the West health insurance should develop influence and capacity
as bulk purchaser or medical and hospital services to impact on quality and cost and provide greater
understanding about Indian health and illness behaviours, patterns of
utilization of care and intra family priorities for accessing medical care.
Health insurance should be welcomed as a force for a fairer healthcare system.
But its success should be judged on how well new products are developed with a
cover beyond hospitalization, how fairly and
inclusively the cover is offered and how far community rated
premiums are established. The IRDA has an immense responsibility and with its
leadership one can optimistically expect
about 30% coverage by 2015 relieving the burden on the public systems.
Post Comment
No comments